Border's theorem explained

In auction theory and mechanism design, Border's theorem gives a necessary and sufficient condition for interim allocation rules (or reduced form auctions) to be implementable via an auction.

It was first proven by Kim Border in 1991,[1] expanding on work from Steven Matthews,[2] Eric Maskin and John Riley.[3] A similar version with different hypotheses was proven by Border in 2007.[4]

Preliminaries

Auctions

Auctions are a mechanism designed to allocate an indivisible good among

N

bidders with private valuation for the good – that is, when the auctioneer has incomplete information on the bidders' true valuation and each bidder knows only their own valuation.

Formally, this uncertainty is represented by a family of probability spaces

(Ti,lTi,λi)

for each bidder

i=1,...,N

, in which each

ti\inTi

represents a possible type (valuation) for bidder

i

to have,

lTi

denotes a σ-algebra on

Ti

, and

λi

a prior and common knowledge probability distribution on

Ti

, which assigns the probability

λi(ti)

that a bidder

i

is of type

ti

. Finally, we define

\boldsymbol{T}=

N
\prod
i=1

Ti

as the set of type profiles, and

\boldsymbol{T}-i=\prodjTi

the set of profiles

t-i=(t1,...,ti-1,ti+1,...,tN)

.

Bidders simultaneously report their valuation of the good, and an auction assigns a probability that they will receive it. In this setting, an auction is thus a function

q:\boldsymbol{T}[0,1]N

satisfying, for every type profile

t\in\boldsymbol{T}

N
\sum
i=1

qi(t)\leq1

where

qi

is the

i

-th component of

q=(q1,q2,...,qN)

. Intuitively, this only means that the probability that some bidder will receive the good is no greater than 1.

Interim allocation rules (reduced form auctions)

From the point of view of each bidder

i

, every auction

q

induces some expected probability that they will win the good given their type, which we can compute as

Qi(ti)=

\int
T-i

qi(t)dλi(t-i|ti)

where

λi(t-i|ti)

is conditional probability of other bidders having profile type

t-i

given that bidder

i

is of type

ti

. We refer to such probabilites

Qi

as interim allocation rules, as they give the probability of winning the auction in the interim period: after each player knowing their own type, but before the knowing the type of other bidders.

The function

\boldsymbolQ:\boldsymbol{T}[0,1]N

defined by

\boldsymbol{Q}(t)=(Q1(t1),...,QN(tN))

is often referred to as a reduced form auction. Working with reduced form auctions is often much more analytically tractable for revenue maximization.

Implementability

Taken on its own, an allocation rule

\boldsymbolQ:T[0,1]N

is called implementable if there exists an auction

q:\boldsymbolT[0,1]N

such that

Qi(ti)=

\int
T-i

qi(t)dλi(t-i|ti)

for every bidder

i

and type

ti\inTi

.

Statement

Border proved two main versions of the theorem, with different restrictions on the auction environment.

i.i.d environment

The auction environment is i.i.d if the probability spaces

(Ti,lTi,λi)=(T,lT,λ)

are the same for every bidder

i

, and types

ti

are independent. In this case, one only needs to consider symmetric auctions, and thus

Qi=Q

also becomes the same for every

i

. Border's theorem in this setting thus states:

Proposition: An interim allocation rule

Q:T[0,1]

is implementable by a symmetric auction if and only if for each measurable set of types

A\inlT

, one has the inequality

N\intAQ(t)dλ(t)\leq1-λ(Ac)N

Intuitively, the right-hand side represents the probability that the winner of the auction is of some type

t\inA

, and the left-hand side represents the probability that there exists some bidder with type

t\inA

. The fact that the inequality is necessary for implementability is intuitive; it being sufficient means that this inequality fully characterizes implementable auctions, and represents the strength of the theorem.

Finite sets of types

If all the sets

Ti

are finite, the restriction to the i.i.d case can be dropped. In the more general environment developed above, Border thus proved:[5]

Proposition: An interim allocation rule

\boldsymbolQ:\boldsymbolT[0,1]N

is implementable by an auction if and only if for each measurable sets of types

A1\inlT1,A2\inlT2,...,AN\inlTN

, one has the inequality
N
\sum
i=1
\int
Ai

Qi(ti)dλi(ti)\leq1-

N
\prod
i=1

\left(1-

\sum
ti\inAi

λi(ti)\right)

The intuition of the i.i.d case remains: the right-hand side represents the probability that the winner of the auction is some bidder

i

with type

ti\inAi

, and the left-hand side represents the probability that there exists some bidder

i

with type

ti\inAi

. Once again, the strength of the result comes from it being sufficient to characterize implementable interim allocation rules.

Notes and References

  1. Border . Kim C. . Implementation of Reduced Form Auctions: A Geometric Approach . Econometrica . 1991 . 59 . 4 . 1175–1187 . 10.2307/2938181 . 2938181 . 3 April 2021 . 0012-9682 . Kim Border.
  2. Matthews . Steven . On the Implementability of Reduced Form Auctions . Econometrica . 1984 . 52 . 6 . 1519–1522. 10.2307/1913517. 10419/220920 . free .
  3. Maskin . Eric . Riley . John . Eric Maskin . Optimal Auctions with Risk Averse Buyers . Econometrica . 1984 . 52 . 6 . 1473–1518 . 10.2307/1913516.
  4. Border . Kim . Kim Border . Reduced form auctions revisited . Economic Theory . 2007 . 31 . 1 . 167–181 . 10.1007/s00199-006-0080-z.
  5. 1 Gopalan. Parikshit. Nisan. Noam . Roughgarden . Tim . Noam Nisan . Tim Roughgarden. 2015. Public projects, Boolean functions and the borders of Border's theorem. 1504.07687. cs.GT.